Political Report # 1424
The Vicissitudes of the Latin American State (Interview)
|
Political theorist Mabel Thwaites Rey discusses the rise and
decline of progressive governments in Latin America, dynamics that spurred the
“end of the cycle,” and characteristics of the new Right.
The impacts of the global economic crisis of 2008 began to
reverberate across South America around 2012, with a number of countries
governed by progressive parties entering into protracted economic downturns.
After a short period of time, this often translated into political defeat at
the hands of the Right, whether through elections, extra-constitutional means,
or an internal rightward drift within governments conceived as part of the
progressive cycle. Coming up in October, near-simultaneous elections in
Argentina, Bolivia, and Uruguay will further impact upon continuities and
ruptures with the “end of the cycle” and the rise of the new Right across the
region. It is a crucial moment to pause and take stalk of both the longer term
and immediate political-economic dynamics underpinning such developments.
With all of this in mind, I had an extended conversation in
Buenos Aires in early May with Mabel Thwaites Rey, professor in the Institute
of Latin American Studies at the University of Buenos Aires, one of the leading
theorists of the Latin American state, and preeminent analyst of the rise and
fall of the progressive tide of social movements and governments in the 21st
century.
In our discussion, we trace the rise of anti-neoliberal
social movements at the turn of the century and the progressive governments
that followed them. Key issues taken up here are the impact of the commodities
boom and the role of the state under new progressive governments, compared to
its role during the orthodox neoliberal era.
Next, we discuss the puzzle of the “end of the cycle.” She
explains the collapse of the progressive cycle with reference, first, to the
central material factor of the global crisis of 2008 and the way its effects
were mediated in Latin America through the collapse of commodity prices. She
explores the social bases and organizational forms assumed by the new
right-wing oppositions, with penetrating insight into the role of the corporate
media, judiciary, and the ideological platform of anti-corruption.
Still, the new right-wing forces are shown to lack the
ideological and political coherence of the Latin American rights of the 1990s,
at the height of neoliberal hegemony. In the absence of such a coherent
project, this might simply mean more violent and draconian forms of right-wing
rule.
Thwaites Rey’s analysis draws fundamentally on a Gramscian
understanding of the state as a social relation. “There is always a tension in
the sense that every conquest can be reversed, a form of subordination,” she
says, “but this does not mean abandoning the struggle to obtain gains which are
translated into the state apparatus in the form of laws, resources, offices.”
In Latin America, she explains, state formation has been intimately tied to the
expansion of global capitalism.
The following interview was conducted in Spanish and has
been condensed and edited for clarity.
Jeffery R. Webber: Can you contextualize historically the
progressive wave of movements and governments that emerged at the outset of the
twenty-first century, and later their decline? What explains the emergence of
many different types of leftist formations and social movements, and out of
them, eventually, progressive governments?
Mabel Thwaites Rey: Together with Hernán Ouviña I edited a
book, Estados en disputa. Auge y fractura del ciclo de impugnación al
neoliberalismo en América Latina (States in Dispute: Rise and Fracture of the
Anti-Neoliberal Cycle in Latin America), which was published earlier this year.
We laid out a series of characteristics of what we called the anti-neoliberal
cycle in Latin America. Our perspective begins its analysis with the surge of
movements of contestation, protest, and popular demands, which accumulated over
the 1990s, the decade of structural adjustment.
Neoliberal adjustments had particularities in each of the
countries of the region and varied in the depth with which they implemented
policies such as privatization of state enterprises, economic liberalization,
and labor market flexibilization. But all were affected by the adjustment wave,
which destroyed our economies and the quality of life of our peoples. In
Argentina, the process of privatizations and deregulation was very drastic,
with an enormous external indebtedness.
Social discontent in the region generated distinct
expressions, with more or less radicalism. In the majority of our countries
there was an eruption of struggles, movements, and unrest that led, towards the
end of the century, to the emergence of governments which echoed these demands
and, to a greater or lesser extent, opposed the neoliberal policies which
preceded them.
There has been much discussion as to how best to
characterize these governments—post-neoliberal, left-wing, progressive. What
binds them, I think, is that all of them, bad or good, challenged, questioned,
confronted—whether rhetorically or more concretely— neoliberalism.
This colored the majority of the political processes of the
region at the start of the new century, and in some countries this was
translated into progressive governments.
An important element is the arrival of Hugo Chávez to power.
He won the 1998 elections, assumed office in 1999, and began to radicalize in
2002, following the failed coup attempt. He put forward a vision of 21st
century socialism and renewed and reinforced the other political processes
underway in the region. The Bolivarian leader represented a regional
breakthrough.
The second element to keep in mind is that this cycle
unfolded in an international context of a rise in commodities prices—a bonanza for
the exporting countries in the region, which are a majority. These countries
benefitted from extraordinary export revenue, whether from grain, energy, or
minerals.
That is not to say that the reactionary cases of Peru,
Chile, or Colombia have been the same as the progressive ones of Brazil,
Argentina, Uruguay, Ecuador, Bolivia, and Venezuela. Even within the latter
countries, the forms of this differential rent were distinct, because this also
has to do with the kind of production involved and what is being exported. It
is not the same thing to appropriate rent from copper or gas and nationalize
these industries, as it is to make use of a part of the rent which comes from
land—as in the case of Argentina—which is privately owned. There is a constant
tension over how to capture this differential rent that comes from the
countryside.
And the third component, which has a common role in the
majority of these processes, is the role of the state. Not because the state
played no powerful and central role in the neoliberal epoch in favour of
capital’s capture of surplus and the disciplining of workers—it did. In the new
period, what national states began to recover was the capacity to arbitrate
between bourgeois fractions, and the capacity of redistribution and mediation
between dominant and popular classes, or between capital and labour.
These are three of the features that we highlighted as
distinctive of the anti-neoliberal cycle, with all of the problems that each
one of them had.
JRW: What was the relationship of these progressive
governments to the leftist social struggles that often preceded them?
MTR: In terms of struggles, we argued that the moment of
apogee of struggles was followed by a period of decline in terms of popular activity.
There are many discussions over why the popular movements diminished, or
whether there were only ever movements from above, propelled by the states
themselves.
Massimo Modonesi has an analysis based in the Gramscian
concept of “passive revolution” and speaks of “pacification.” He argues that
what the governments produced was a capture, a subsumption of the energy of the
insurrectionary popular initiative, in order to redirect it toward bourgeois
re-composition. So, he speaks of passive revolutions, in a progressive sense
because they made concessions, but they maintained intact the structure of
capital.
While we say that at the base of the anti-neoliberal cycle,
as a whole, were the protests and demands of the popular struggles begun in the
1990s, the progressive governments that followed did not arrive in office on
the tail of an immediate boost of popular struggles. The exception is Bolivia,
which is the clearest case of a consistent popular mobilization that flows into
the government of Evo Morales. In the majority of cases there were mediations.
In Argentina, the crisis was in 2001-2002, and in 2003 the
process was channelled politically by a fraction of Peronism. In Ecuador the
Citizen’s Revolution was protagonized by urban middle classes and not the
Pachakutic Indigenous movement. In Venezuela, it’s not true that there was a
great process of popular activity. On the contrary, it is from the leadership
of the state that Chávez began to promote popular participation. Therefore, to
speak of “pacification” in the Venezuelan case is to simplify a more complex
situation, since more than “pacification,” there was an attempt at activation.
In the cases of Brazil and Uruguay, the governments that
came to office were constituted by centre-left coalitions that had been
combative at one time, but which at a certain moment—in the case of the PT it
is especially clear—made political alliances and moderated their public
discourse in order to win elections. So, they don’t come to office on the peak
of a grand participatory wave that one could say was subsequently “pacified”
purposefully by the state leadership. In any case, they can still be reproached
for how little they did to activate popular participation from the state in
order to deepen changes.
Another aspect to consider is that there is no possibility
of governing and of stable political leadership if there is no attempt to
articulate and calm certain exacerbations of demands and internal struggles.
JRW: Can you speak more on the impact of the commodity boom
and its decline?
MTR: What [the limits of the commodity boom] produced was
the paradox of deepening the existing productive schemas. Extractivism,
mono-production, and deindustrialization were all accelerated as an effect of
the external boom.
In Brazil, this dynamic is very clear. In those years the
industrial contribution to GDP fell while the proportion constituted by
agricultural production increased. This is apparent in the tendency of
“soyization”—the expansion of land devoted to the cultivation of soy—with all
of the conflicts that it brought with it, and to the detriment of fomenting
other more integrated forms of production that could also keep in mind
environmental criteria.
It’s clear that this cycle allowed the capture of surplus
and the redistribution of part of it. It was important to the deepening of
social policies and, in some cases like Argentina—and not only there—it
enhanced the axis of consumption and employment. That is, after decades of
increasing unemployment and pauperization, to guarantee access to levels of
consumption and employment for the popular sectors was central to winning
hegemony, and the political project of Kirchnerism was based on this.
Some analysts argue that these years were characterized by a
“commodities consensus,” ie., that the prevailing ruling pact was to maintain
mining and agro-industrial extractivism, without distinction among national
political projects. We argue, on the contrary, that what prevailed was a pact
to sustain consumption and employment, as a way of ensuring legitimacy.
JRW: In your view, what are the most important institutional
characteristics of these states across this period, and how do they relate to
the mechanisms and limits of structural transformation?
MTR: Another aspect to keep in mind is the institutional
question. While in a few processes, which because of the level of pre-existing
political decomposition, required or enabled constitutional reforms—as in
Bolivia, Ecuador and Venezuela—in the rest, there was not change in the basis
of political organization. And even in those three cases which had
constitutional reforms, the formats of political representation remained more
or less unaltered.
They maintained the schema of classical representative democracy,
with periodic elections, and without modifications or amplification in
participation. This had the strength of regular popular consultation, but also
the negative of closing off other instances that could have given a greater
stability to deeper processes of transformation.
So, it is also clear that when one critiques the absence of
structural transformations or that the rent from the resources of the bonanza
cycle were used without altering the underlying productive matrix, it’s
necessary to keep in mind that, if they had not distributed that rent they
would have lost political support, and if that happened, the opponent that
promised to do so would have won, even if they were lying. That is why we
believe that the central issue is how to produce processes of transformation,
which necessarily require a larger appropriation of the surplus to be directed
toward other policies of a longer-term nature, when there are very immediate,
very pressing demands to satisfy.
The process of transformation generates a constant tension,
where in each country there are distinct bottle necks in the productive
structure, which can become more acute to the extent that the sustaining
material bases are not transformed. And how are these material bases built? One
question that could be asked is why stronger popular support for structural
changes could not be built.
One of the axes that we explain in the book and which we
continue to work on is the dimension of consumption, which is structured at the
global level. That is, the forms and devices of consumption defined at the
global scale are a material factor of the capitalist system, much stronger than
we sometimes want to accept. They are very powerful devices in terms of
cultural construction, of ideological cement.
JRW: So, now that we have discussed some of the vagaries of
the progressive wave at its height, when and why did the so-called “end of the
cycle” begin?
MTR: There are general economic elements at the root of the
end of the cycle. Latin America was initially able to counter the effects of
crisis of global capitalism of 2008, but beginning in 2011 problems were
accentuated, and by 2013 serious problems appeared in almost every country of
the region. Bolivia was the most successful at circumventing the crisis, through
its fairly orthodox budget, as distinct from Ecuador and Venezuela, which could
not avoid the blow. In Brazil and Argentina, too, the crisis began to hit
strongly, with the fall in grain prices. Symptoms of great weakness began to
appear, which made the more structural problems of each country more acute.
The year 2013 is key: Dilma was re-elected in Brazil and
immediately applied an adjustment plan that ran contrary to what she had
announced in her campaign, sparking a chain of protests and irruptions of
discontent which the Right was able to capitalize on. And to this was added the
death of Chávez. I think that just as one can mark the beginning of the cycle
with the arrival of Hugo Chávez to office, his death in 2013 was a very
powerful moment of political inflection for the region. All the limits that the
Bolivarian process already had were made more acute following the death of its
leader.
In 2013, protests appeared in Brazil over the transport
system. This was followed by Indigenous protests in Ecuador, and protests in
Argentina led by segments of unionized workers demanding a reduction in the
taxes on their wages, and upper-middle- and upper-class sectors that expanded
their anti-populist rejection of the government. These comfortable layers began
to take to the streets, especially in Venezuela, Brazil, and Argentina, under
the banners of security and anti-corruption.
JRW: Can you explain the role of anti-corruption campaigns
as a kind of adhesive glue of right-wing oppositions?
MTR: An alliance became visible between the corporate media,
important segments of judicial power, and the intelligence services,
articulated with the United States, around the use of corruption as a lethal
weapon to be wielded against these governments. Already in an adverse economic
context, corruption scandals—some real, others unfounded—began to appear as
instruments of political struggle and judicial intervention. However, the
underestimation of the importance of corruption in public opinion on the part
of progressive governments is also clear. It is not acceptable that there are
individuals who are in governmental positions or in high positions of power who
exhibit ostentatious self-enrichment, and the importance of this was
underestimated.
In almost all of the processes, the mainstream media assumed
a leading organizational role in the right-wing opposition. It has long been
well known that these media corporations are engaged in the economic game; but
this time, their role as the principal organizers of the social and political
right-wing opposition to progressive governments became very apparent. In
contrast to the illusion that social media would counter the power of
traditional media and would guarantee a democratic circulation of information
and opinion, media concentration in its digital form proved to be very
powerful.
In that context of social and political dispute, the
economic crisis made these governments more vulnerable, and a very strong
process of political degradation began in the region. The first landmark was
the electoral triumph of Mauricio Macri in Argentina in October 2015. He was
able to win at the ballot box by a very slim margin and began to implement
substantive neoliberal changes, bringing the country into its present social
and economic crisis. He applied, simultaneously, a monetarist plan of
containing inflation and a strategy of massive indebtedness, with the declared
objective of attracting foreign investment. Both strategies led to disaster,
with unstoppable inflation, exorbitant interest rates, devaluation, recession,
unemployment, and an unsustainable debt that led to a request for assistance
from the International Monetary Fund.
JRW: Beyond the case of Macri, how do you characterize the
new right-wing wave in the region? We have Macri, Bolsonaro, Piñera, and
others—different inflections in different countries. What are the common
characteristics across the different scenarios, as well as the most important
particularities?
MTR: What one seems to notice is the degree of intolerance
that certain middle and high social sectors have in the face of minimal
processes of reform. It’s a fear that seems exaggerated in the face of measures
that, for us, do not imply any deep transformation. However, they provoke an
irritation and rejection much stronger than is warranted.
In some cases, it was the inflammation of the rhetoric
deployed by leaders that generated such a strong antagonism. The reaction of
the Latin American Rights is worrying, because they have shown themselves to be
extremely bellicose in the face of everything that appears to be popular or
left-wing. In Europe, the Left is hated because they defend immigrants; here,
what is hated is the pretence of egalitarianism. And they use the argument of
corruption—which undoubtedly exists—as an excuse to attack “the popular” in all
of its manifestations. It is obvious that corruption is merely an excuse,
otherwise they could not accept figures like Macri, who comes from a family
which has enriched itself through dubious contracts with the state; Macri
himself has been accused of contraband trading, he has offshore companies that
featured in the Panama Papers, and he publicly admitted—15 days after his
father’s death—that his father had paid bribes to advance his business
interests.
An issue that binds the various Rights is that of security
and repression. In Argentina, for example, they rail against garantismo, the
legal system which guarantees human rights and prohibits brutal repression.
This was always interpreted by the right as a defence of criminals, and as a
counter to this they demand an “iron fist.” This is also the case in Brazil,
where it is more accentuated because of the explicit component of racism.
Furthermore, I think that one doesn’t need to be a
conspiracy theorist to understand that the U.S. State Department, through its
embassies, military attachés, and intelligence services, operated and continues
to operate against whatever political force that minimally challenges its
interests. The arrival of Trump accelerated this process, albeit with
contradictory and complicated results, because he is so brutal that he
frightens his own officials. In any case, U.S. interests are present.
JRW: Although all of these new or reconfigured parties of
the Right have managed to attain office, they have no plausible exit of their
own to the present economic crisis, and the dynamics of the world market are
hardly favourable to their chances of success. Bolsonaro’s popularity is down
to 30 percent, and Macri’s government is in full throated crisis and his
prospects are dim in the October elections. Given these kinds of dynamics, what
is the probability that this new Right will endure for an extended period?
MTR: I think there is a very important difference between
the neoliberal wave of the 1990s and the present. In the 1990s, there was a
strong intellectual, political, and economic density to the Right. There was a
promise that applying specific measures of the Washington
Consensus—privatization, deregulation, liberalization, fiscal discipline—would
produce notable improvements. And, above all, globalization was the promising
banner of an integrated and happy world. They said that globalization would
allow us access to different markets and that the sovereignty of the consumer
would prevail. It was a very powerful promise of welfare, which assured people
that prosperity would come once the limits of the social welfare state were
overcome.
In Latin America, the project arrived “key in hand,” with
recipes indicating the necessary policies to apply. The loans from the World
Bank, the Inter-American Development Bank, and the United Nations Development
Program arrived with procedural manuals, including how to run the state.
Today, it seems that the various Rights have no clear path.
There is nothing that can be exhibited as the lovely way forward, a source of
enthusiasm that could generate some illusion about the future. There isn’t one.
They don’t have one because the consequences of the crisis are so terrible and
permanent adjustment policies are not such an enchanting offer. Just the
opposite. What is worrying, however, is that this exacerbates another type of
Right—more brutal, more xenophobic, more anti-popular, and more disposed to use
force and violence, which is what we are beginning to witness.
Jeffery R. Webber is
presently a Senior Lecturer of International Political Economy at Goldsmiths,
University of London. He will take up a new position in the Department of
Politics at York University, Toronto in January 2020. His latest book is The
Last Day of Oppression, and the First Day of the Same: The Politics and
Economics of the New Latin American Left. He is presently at work on The Latin
American Crucible: Politics and Power in the New Era, under contract with
Verso.
Original article can be found (here). URL: Click here for article |
No comments:
Post a Comment